The lovely tale of Liquor
during Lockdown and before
At every stage, addiction is driven by one of the most powerful, mysterious, and
vital forces of human existence. What drives addiction is longing —
a longing not just of brain, belly, or loins but finally of the heart.
Cornelius Platinga
​
The use of alcohol in India for drinking purposes dates back to somewhere between 3000 and 2000 BC. An alcoholic beverage called Sura which was distilled from the rice was popular at that time in India for common men to unwind at the end of a stressful day. . Yet the first mention of Alcohol appears in Rig Veda (1700BC). It mentions intoxicants like soma and prahamana. Although the soma plant might not exist today, it was famous for delivering a euphoric high. It was also recorded in the Samhita, the medical compendium of Sushruta that he who drinks soma will not age and will be impervious to fire, poison, or weapon attack. The sweet juice of Soma was also said to help establish a connection with the gods. Such was the popularity of alcohol. Initially used for medicinal purposes, with time it evolved and became the beverage that brought life to social gatherings, and eventually consuming alcohol has become a habit for many.
With such a rich history of not just humans but also of the gods,
what is a worldwide pandemic to stop anybody from drinking?
. . .
​
According to a report released by the World Health Organisation (WHO) in 2018, an average Indian drinks approximately 5.7 liters of alcohol every year. In a population of casual and excessive drinkers, with the shutters of liquor stores down, it must have been extremely difficult for “certain” people to survive lockdown. In the first two phases of lockdown, the desperation had quadrupled prices of alcohol in the Grey Market of India. Also, According to Google Trends, online searches for “how to make alcohol at home” peaked in India during the fourth week of March, which was the same when the lockdown was announced. As a consequence, a few people died drinking home-brewed liquor. People committed suicide due to alcohol withdrawal syndrome. Owing to the worsening situation and to reboot the economy, some states decided to open licensed liquor stores in the third phase of the COVID-19 Pandemic lockdown in India. This decision was the worst best decision the state governments could take. The kilometer-long queues in front of liquor stores were evidence that a pandemic can turn your life upside down yet your relationship with alcohol cannot move an inch.
The love in the hearts of those who are addicted was explicit. We might have seen addiction, we might have witnessed desperation but what happened in the month of May was madness, not just in terms of the way people pounced but also in the way the government earned. According to a report by Hindustan Times, on the first day of the third phase of Lockdown, the Indian state of Uttar Pradesh recorded a sale of over Rs 100 Crore from liquor. On the second day of the reopening of Liquor stores, Karnataka reported sales of 197 crores in a single day which was the largest ever. Eventually, the prices of Liquor were hiked to 100% to discourage people from drinking.
. . .
​
There was a special corona fee that was imposed in Delhi by Chief Minister Arvind Kejriwal. A 70% corona fee was imposed in Delhi, yet the sales did not drop. The entire situation was a disaster for the law enforcement officers, social distancing was easily abandoned and a basic code of conduct was happily violated. Despite the chaos created, the states continued to collect revenues. Home delivery of alcohol was allowed in Maharashtra and e-tokens were sold in Delhi.
​
Demand for liquor is inelastic which means that
the sale of alcohol is not much responsive to change in prices.
In general, since alcohol policy is a state subject in India, revenue from Liquor is a cash cow for state governments. In 2018 and 2019, four states collectively collected about 20,000 crores in taxes from the sale of liquor. As much as the state earns from the sale of Liquor it is undoubtedly, a threat to the Economy. Consumption of alcohol has dire health consequences. When a person consumes an alcoholic beverage, there is a rise in BAC because of which there is a gradual and progressive loss of driving ability because of an increase in reaction time, overconfidence, degraded muscle coordination, impaired concentration, and decreased auditory and visual acuity. This is known as drunken driving. (V. M. Anantha Eashwar, 2020) Drunken driving is the third biggest cause of road accidents and over speeding in India. Road accidents are not it; alcoholism causes sleep problems, heart, and liver issues. Also, it is not about an individual’s life, it ruins the lives of all people concerned.
Addiction also causes economic loss. In 2000, Vivek Benegal and his team assessed 113 patients admitted to a special de-addiction service for alcohol dependence. They found that
the average individual earned a mean of ₹1,661 but
spent ₹1,938 per month on alcohol, incurring high debt.
They also found that 95% did not work for about 14 days in a month. They concluded that it led to a loss of ₹13,823 per person per year in terms of foregone productivity. A more recent study, Health Impact and Economic Burden of Alcohol Consumption in India, led by Gaurav Jyani, concluded that alcohol-attributable deaths would lead to a loss of 258 million life-years between 2011 and 2050. The study placed the economic burden on the health system at $48.11 billion, and the societal burden (including health costs, productivity loss, and so on) at $1,867 billion. “This amounts to an average loss of 1.45% of the gross domestic product (GDP) per year to the Indian economy,” the study said. (Mint, 2020)
Setho ka Gaon

With each passing day, the ‘curtain of separation’ weighs down on the women of Afghanistan, paving the way for tyranny to thrive.
Arth

The Economics of the Farm Bills of 2020

Vasu Golyan
5 mins read
As our country gets deeper and deeper into the consequences of the grave mismanagement of the pandemic by our national leadership, the government faces another round of backlash on a policy that directly affects those who practice the country's largest employing occupation and form the backbone of the economy--agriculture.
​
The worst effects of the protests have been seen in the states of Haryana & Punjab (states which collect significant tax revenue from the APMCs) manifested in the form of strikes, road blockages, and rallies. These laws are seen as a move that would lead to the 'corporatization' of agriculture and are a threat to the entire network of agriculture, farmers-market, and revenue distribution models at a national level. It is expected to begin the transition of a monopsony-driven agricultural system to a free-market agrarian economy. In this piece, we briefly look over what do the three bills entail, how the farmers and the masses have perceived them, and to whom exactly are these a boon and a bane.
The Argument against - The ones whom the Bills Hurt
​
. . .
​
Who is hurt the most, and Why?
These bills have seen the most outrage from farmers in Punjab & Haryana mainly because these two states combined account for more than half of all the agri-produce procurement by the government. More than three-fourths of the produce from these states are purchased as minimum-support-prices; hence, farmers in these states argue that without MSP regulations, market prices will fall instead of rising.
​
The state governments have sided with the farmers' protests in these states because of their high investments in developing the APMC & Mandi networks and in connecting roads between rural-villages and markets. Mandi tax at 6% contributes to a large chunk of the state annual revenue with a contribution of ₹3,500 crores.
​
How will farmers' MSP be impacted?
Much like the states mentioned above, MSP has been a central issue of all protests. However, an important point drowned amidst all the public & political action & emotion is the fact that the centre only engages in the purchase of wheat, paddy, and a few pulses based on MSP.
What's even more striking is that nationally only 6%
of all the country's farmers sell their produce at MSP rates.
Under the newly proposed bills, the MSP regime remains untouched. A notable contention from the farmer's end has been regarding the lack of any legislation on the enforcement of MSP at a universal level - demanding that MSP be applicable to both government and private players and there should be a legally enforceable 'floor price', below which purchases by any party cannot be made from the farmers.
​
On a different avenue, these laws can affect the government procurement procedure--state procurements are made at key allotted APMC mandis, and a prevailing fear is that the promotion of tax-free private means of purchase could very well render public procurement at the APMC mandis unviable. This could disrupt a reliable source of market demand for the farmers and also hurt government welfare schemes (PDS), contingent on such procurement and supply.
​
. . .
​
A Biased Playing Field
Looking at this issue from a Laissez-faire perspective, we see that there are about 7000 APMC mandis operational in the country. Most private players operating in this sector in the form of small-scale traders operate within the bounds of APMCs. However, with the deregulation of markets in the form of deregulation and unrestricted purchase sizes, we can expect the entry of larger corporate players into the segment. This can very well skew the entire playing field in their favor and make the market biased against the farmers by pulling leverage away from them. The contention here, then becomes one of the isolated bargaining powers and abilities of individual farmers, against organized and often exploitative bargaining powers by MNCs. The similar experience of farmers in countries such as Brazil and the US stands as a grim reminder of how poorly informed farmers can fall prey to the predatory pricing tactics of MNCs, in the absence of any state regulation.
​
Whom does the Bill benefit?
A Sectoral Productivity Boost
The government expects the bills to transform the agriculture sector and pull it out of its low-productivity-low-investment trap. These bills are in line with the centre’s ambitious plan to double the farmers' income by 2022. The introduction of free-market economics to the procurement of agricultural produce will introduce efficiency, weed-out intermediaries, and bring domestic prices in-line with prevailing international prices, at least to some extent.
​
These expected improvements mean that the farmer gets a
higher share of what the consumer pays for the produce.
The bills also encourage intra-state trade and allow the farmers to sell to the best-bidder, rather than just selling to the only bidder, i.e., the government in the earlier system. Further, the Bill formulates a framework on the agreements that enable farmers to engage with agri-business companies, retailers, exporters for service, and sale of products while giving the farmer access to modern technology. The implementation of the bills will see items such as cereals and pulses being removed from the list of essential commodities and therefore, attract FDI into the sector.
​
Agri-tech Start-ups & Economic Benefits
The most revolutionary impact of the bills would be on the small and marginal farmers with less than five hectares of land. They will clear up the regulatory bottlenecks surrounding agricultural produce and enable the price-discovery mechanism for small and marginal farmers. A major beneficiary here would be the agri-tech start-ups, who specialize in digitalization, data-led crop advisory services, intermediary elimination, and improved marketing and market linkages. The contract farming norms in the new bills are expected to benefit such agri-tech businesses, who can bridge the gap between the unorganized farmers and the MNCs.
​
Not only would these start-ups help in eliminating intermediaries, but crop-processing capabilities, cold-storages, and consumer choices are all set to improve. A slew of new start-ups is also expected to come up to capture this new market, i.e., that of non-APMC-cantered agricultural trade. Thus, if all goes well, through the significant improvement in procurement infrastructure, product marketing, price-discovery, and production efficiency, the small and marginal farmers are expected to gain the most, with the agri-tech start-ups leading the waves of change.
. . .
​
Conclusion
The impact that the new laws will have on the Indian farmer will all depend upon how the free-market experience turns out. Even though the intention behind the laws is to be praised, serious concerns remain with respect to its public acceptability as well as viability in the face of established and well-accepted systems. However, if the experience of other countries is something to go by, and the added peculiarities of the Indian agricultural system coupled with the notoriously corrupt implementation of laws in India, the new farmer bills can have an effect opposite to that originally intended. The farmers, in the absence of any substantive bargaining power, will quickly fall prey to predatory pricing by the MNCs, and in the absence of APMCs (if they are rendered unviable by the private sector), will be forced to sell at abysmally low prices.
Therefore, it is not just the federal structure of the country or the tax revenue of individual states that is put at stake by these laws, but also the future and livelihood of the nation's most important, yet most abused profession: agriculture.